xsolve {AssetPricing} | R Documentation |
Optimal pricing policy
Description
Determines (by solving a coupled system of differential equations) the optimal prices as functions of (residual) time for a number perishable assets. Prices may be discrete or continuous. For continuous prices, the price sensitivity function may either be a smooth (twice differentiable) function or a function which is piecewise linear in price.
Usage
xsolve(S, lambda, gprob=1, tmax=NULL, qmax, prices=NULL, nout=300,
type="sip", alpha=NULL, salval=0, epsilon=NULL,
method="lsoda",verbInt=0)
Arguments
S |
An expression, or list of expressions, or a function or list
of functions, specifying the price sensitivity functions
|
lambda |
A function (of residual time |
gprob |
A function (to calculate probabilities) or a numeric vector of probabilities determining the distribution of the size of an arriving group of customers. |
tmax |
The maximum residual time; think of this as being the initial time
at which the assets go on sale (with time decreasing to zero,
at which point the value of each asset drops to the “salvage
value” ( |
qmax |
The maximum number of assets available for sale, i.e. the number
of assets available at the starting (residual) time |
prices |
A numeric vector (with positive values) listing the possible prices at which items may be offered for sale in the discrete pricing scenario. |
nout |
The number of points at which values of the solution are to be
provided. These are taken to be equispaced on
[0, |
type |
Scalar character string taking one of the two values |
alpha |
A numeric scalar between 0 and 1 specifying the probability that an
arriving group of size |
salval |
A (non-negative) numeric scalar specifying the “salvage
value” of an asset — i.e. the quantity to which the value of an
asset drops at residual time |
epsilon |
A numeric scalar used in determining the optimal price
in settings in which this involves maximizing over a discrete set.
See Details. It defaults to |
method |
Character string specified the solution method to be used
by the differential equation solver |
verbInt |
A scalar value which controls “verbosity”.
If |
Details
If prices are modelled as being continuous, and if the price
sensitivity function is differentiable, a coupled system
of differential equations for the optimal prices is solved.
If the prices are modelled as being discrete or if the price
sensitivity function is piecewise linear in price, then a
coupled system of differential equations for the expected
value of the stock is solved, with the optimal price being
determined at each step by maximizing over an appropriate finite
discrete set. These differential equations are solved by the
ode()
function from the deSolve
package.
The components of the argument S
should be provided as
expressions when the price sensitivity functions are assumed to
be smooth, and these should be amenable to differentiation with
respect to x
and t
via the function deriv3()
.
Note that in general the expression or expressions will depend upon
a number of parameters as well as upon x
and t
.
The values of these parameters are specified via an attribute or
attributes. If S
is a (single) expression it has (must have)
an attribute called parvec
which is a named vector of
parameter values. If S
is a list of expressions each entry
of the list has (must have) such an attribute.
In the “piecewise linear” context S
can be
specified only as a single function. It is then assumed
that the price sensitivity function for a group of size j
is given by S_j(x,t) = S(x,t)^j
. Such piecewise linear
price sensitivity functions should be built using the function
buildS()
.
In the case of discrete prices the argument S
must be a
function or list of functions specifying the price sensitivity
functions S_j(x,t)
. These functions need only be defined
for the prices listed in the prices
argument.
If S
is a single expression or function, then
S_j(x,t)
is taken to be this expression or function raised
to the power j
. If S
is a list, then S_j(x,t)
is taken to be its j
-th entry.
In the case where argument S
is a piecewise linear
price sensitivity function, the argument tmax
is, if not
specified, taken to be the value of the corresponding attribute
of S
. In this setting, if tmax
is specified
it must be less than or equal to the corresponding attribute
of S
.
For discrete prices and for piecewise linear price sensitivity functions, determining the optimal price involves maximizing expected values over finite discrete sets. It can happen that the location of the maximum can make a sudden “jump” from one time step to the next, causing anomalous looking discontinuities in the optimal price functions. To avoid this, we check on the change in the expected value at each of the possible new prices as compared with that at the “previous” price.
If the maximal “improvement” in expected value is less
than or equal to epsilon
then the “new” price is
set equal to the previous value. If the maximal improvement
is greater than epsilon
then those values of price,
where the expected value is greater than the maximum value minus
epsilon
, are considered and the one which is closest to
the previous price is chosen.
If epsilon
is set equal to a value less than or equal to
0
then the smoothing strategy described above is dispensed
with. In this case the maximum is taken to be the first of the
(possibly) multiple maxima of the expected value.
Value
A list with components:
x |
The optimal pricing policy, chosen to maximize the expected
value of the remaining assets at any given time; an object of
class In the case of continuous prices these functions will be
continuous functions created by Note that |
v |
An object of class |
vdot |
An object of class |
Note
A substantial change was made to this package as of the change
of version number from 0.0-11 to 0.1-0. Previously the differential
equations which arise were solved via a “locally produced”
roll-your-own Runge-Kutta procedure. Now they are solved (in a
more sophisticated manner) using the package deSolve
. This
increases the solution speed by a factor of about 7. There will
be (minor, it is to be hoped) numerical differences in solutions
produced from the same input.
Progress Reports
The “progress reports” produced when verbInt > 0
consist of rough estimates of the percentage of [0,tmax]
(the interval over which the differential equation is being solved)
remaining to be covered. A rough estimate of the total elapsed
time since the solution process started is also printed out.
Having “progress reports” printed out appears to have no (or at worst negligible) impact on computation time.'
Author(s)
Rolf Turner r.turner@auckland.ac.nz http://www.stat.auckland.ac.nz/~rolf
References
P. K. Banerjee, and T. R. Turner (2012). A flexible model for the pricing of perishable assets. Omega 40:5, 533–540. DOI https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2011.10.001
Rolf Turner, Pradeep Banerjee and Rayomand Shahlori (2014). Optimal Asset Pricing. Journal of Statistical Software 58:11, 1–25. DOI https://doi.org/10.18637/jss.v058.i11
See Also
vsolve()
, plot.AssetPricing()
,
buildS()
Examples
#
# In these examples "qmax" has been set equal to 5 which is
# an unrealistically low value for the total number of assets.
# This is done so as to reduce the time for package checking on CRAN.
#
# Smooth price sensitivity function.
S <- expression(exp(-kappa*x/(1+gamma*exp(-beta*t))))
attr(S,"parvec") <- c(kappa=10/1.5,gamma=9,beta=1)
# Optimal pricing policy assuming customers arrive singly:
lambda1 <- function(tt){
84*(1-tt)
}
X1 <- xsolve(S=S,lambda=lambda1,gprob=1,tmax=1,qmax=5,
type="sip",verbInt=5)
# Optimal pricing policy assuming customers arrive in groups of
# size up to 5, with group size probabilities 1/3, 4/15, 1/5, 2/15,
# and 1/15 respectively.
lambda2 <- function(tt){
36*(1-tt)
}
X2 <- xsolve(S=S,lambda=lambda2,gprob=(5:1)/15,tmax=1,qmax=5,
type="sip", alpha=0.5,verbInt=5)
# Note that the intensity functions lambda1() and lambda2() are
# such that the expected total number of customers is 42 in each case.
# Discrete prices:
lambda3 <- function(t){42}
S <- function(x,t){
e <- numeric(2)
e[x==1] <- exp(-2*t)
e[x==0.6] <- 1.0
e
}
X3 <- xsolve(S=S,lambda=lambda3,gprob=1,tmax=1,qmax=5,prices=c(1,0.6),
type="sip",verbInt=5)
# Piecewise linear price sensitivity function.
#
# Take S as in the example for buildS.
# This takes a loonnngggg time; the procedure is slow
# in the piecewise linear setting.
## Not run:
l0 <- get("lambda",envir=environment(get("alpha",envir=environment(S))[[1]]))
lambda4 <- function(t){apply(l0(t),1,sum)}
X4 <- xsolve(S=S,lambda=lambda4,gprob=(5:1)/15,qmax=30,type="sip",
alpha=0.5,verbInt=20)
## End(Not run)